JavaScript is disabled in your web browser or browser is too old to support JavaScript. Today almost all web pages contain JavaScript, a scripting programming language that runs on visitor's web browser. It makes web pages functional for specific purposes and if disabled for some reason, the content or the functionality of the web page can be limited or unavailable.

Friday, March 14, 2025

PM Mottley to IMF: Reform lending arrangements for middle-income countries

by

281 days ago
20240606
Barbados Prime Minister Mia Mottley

Barbados Prime Minister Mia Mottley

When con­sid­er­ing the eco­nom­ic and de­vel­op­ment chal­lenges of de­vel­op­ing economies in the face of the cli­mate cri­sis, most peo­ple tend to view debt as a com­pli­cat­ing fac­tor at best, and a source of many of our prob­lems at worst.

There are good rea­sons for this. Ris­ing pub­lic debt across the de­vel­op­ing world – and the surg­ing in­ter­est bills that ac­com­pa­ny it -is di­vert­ing pub­lic funds from al­ready un­der­fund­ed health and ed­u­ca­tion pro­grammes. It threat­ens to push more coun­tries in­to out­right dis­tress and more peo­ple back in­to pover­ty.

Yet there is no es­cap­ing the fact that debt will con­tin­ue to be a crit­i­cal com­po­nent of the fund­ing de­vel­op­ing economies need to meet their sus­tain­able de­vel­op­ment goals – par­tic­u­lar­ly cli­mate re­silience – and ful­fill their eco­nom­ic de­vel­op­ment po­ten­tial more gen­er­al­ly. The chal­lenge, there­fore, is to both lend and bor­row “bet­ter.”

What does this mean?

Well, for sure it means en­sur­ing that pub­lic bor­row­ing is an­chored in sus­tained fis­cal dis­ci­pline. How­ev­er, it al­so means avoid­ing debt that is very like­ly to prove un­sus­tain­able. While over­all debt sus­tain­abil­i­ty is de­ter­mined by mul­ti­ple fac­tors, ex­pe­ri­ence teach­es us that the rate of eco­nom­ic growth is the most im­por­tant dri­ver of debt dy­nam­ics.

There is a sim­ple rule to help de­ter­mine when the terms of new bor­row­ing are un­like­ly to prove sus­tain­able over time, at least when it comes to cost: put sim­ply, rates of in­ter­est that are like­ly to ex­ceed the rate of fu­ture nom­i­nal growth can­not be con­sid­ered sus­tain­able. The more such rates fea­ture across a pub­lic debt port­fo­lio, the greater the like­li­hood of sov­er­eign debt dis­tress in the fu­ture.

Flawed frame­work

Al­though there has been much fo­cus on the very high in­ter­est rates paid by some de­vel­op­ing economies on their Eu­robond is­suances since the start of 2024, the prob­lem of un­sus­tain­ably high bor­row­ing costs is al­so ev­i­dent in lend­ing by the of­fi­cial sec­tor.

In fact, the re­cent rise in glob­al in­ter­est rates has re­vealed a flawed IMF lend­ing frame­work for mid­dle-in­come coun­tries that no longer sup­ports debt sus­tain­abil­i­ty. It is in des­per­ate need of re­form.

Let’s start with the cen­tral is­sue of cost. At the start of the mil­len­ni­um, sur­charges were in­tro­duced on all IMF lend­ing to mid­dle-in­come coun­tries through the Gen­er­al Re­sources Ac­count (GRA), which in­cludes Stand-by Arrange­ments (SBAs), Ex­tend­ed Fund Fa­cil­i­ties (EFFs), and Rapid Fi­nanc­ing In­stru­ments (RFIs).

The sur­charge struc­ture com­pris­es a lev­el-based sur­charge of 2 per cent on GRA bor­row­ing that ex­ceeds 187.5 per cent of quo­ta and an ad­di­tion­al one per cent “time-based” sur­charge on the por­tion of GRA cred­it above this thresh­old that is out­stand­ing for more than 36 months (or 51 months in the case of the EFFs).

The IMF in­tro­duced these sur­charges when it was try­ing to ex­tin­guish the flames of the first emerg­ing mar­ket debt crises, in­clud­ing by burn­ing through its own cap­i­tal. The un­der­ly­ing ob­jec­tive of the new sur­charges was to dis­suade large and pro­longed bor­row­ing from de­plet­ing the IMF’s re­sources, par­tic­u­lar­ly among high­er-rat­ed emerg­ing mar­ket sov­er­eign bor­row­ers.

The sur­charges worked well, and these coun­tries quick­ly re­gained in­vest­ment grade rat­ings af­ter the cri­sis. Years lat­er, the ap­proach worked well again: Or­gan­i­sa­tion for Eco­nom­ic Co-op­er­a­tion and De­vel­op­ment coun­tries that had been forced to bor­row from the Fund dur­ing the glob­al fi­nan­cial cri­sis were able to pre­pay their IMF li­a­bil­i­ties once the worst of the in­sta­bil­i­ty prob­lems had sub­sided, thanks to deep do­mes­tic cap­i­tal mar­kets.

But the world has changed rad­i­cal­ly over the past 25 years. For a start, the IMF has gone from hav­ing pre­cau­tion­ary bal­ances of US$6.2 bil­lion as of April 1999 to ap­prox­i­mate­ly $33 bil­lion as of April 2024.

It has al­so suc­ceed­ed in mak­ing a much-need­ed piv­ot, grad­u­al­ly ex­pand­ing its role as a lender of last re­sort to be­come a part­ner of some of the poor­er and most frag­ile coun­tries in the world at a time when their ac­cess to liq­uid­i­ty has been se­vere­ly com­pro­mised.

The scale of IMF lend­ing has al­so in­creased. In fact, 187.5 per­cent of quo­ta is no longer a big deal: as of April this year, 21 mid­dle-in­come coun­tries had bor­rowed above this lev­el from the Fund. Com­pared with a decade ago, the av­er­age per capi­ta in­come of coun­tries with ac­tive EFFs has fall­en by a fac­tor of 4.

Yet the Fund’s sur­charge regime re­mains un­changed and has ex­posed frag­ile sov­er­eign bor­row­ers to the full force of ris­ing world in­ter­est rates, even though the IMF is now well cap­i­talised and does not re­ly on mar­ket bor­row­ing to fund its lend­ing arrange­ments.

Sur­charge regime

As of June this year, the min­i­mum all-in in­ter­est rate payable on GRA dis­burse­ments (this cov­ers SBA, EFF, and RFI dis­burse­ments) had surged to 5.1 per cent a year, with sov­er­eigns pay­ing 7.1 per cent on the por­tion of their draw­ings that ex­ceeds 187.5 per­cent of quo­ta.

GRA li­a­bil­i­ties out­stand­ing for three years or more (or four in the case of the EFF- less than halfway to fi­nal ma­tu­ri­ty) now have a record in­ter­est rate of 8.1 per cent.

The IMF can­not ar­gue that its lend­ing pro­grammes have debt sus­tain­abil­i­ty at heart when its own lend­ing to mid­dle-in­come coun­tries can­not be con­sid­ered sus­tain­able.

This is a prob­lem the IMF must ad­dress. In­cen­tivis­ing sov­er­eign bor­row­ers to re­pay the IMF is not wrong in it­self, but it is wrong in a world where most GRA bor­row­ers have no re­li­able ac­cess to al­ter­na­tive sources of sus­tain­able fi­nanc­ing.

The IMF’s sur­charge regime needs to be re­formed ur­gent­ly-ei­ther through a rad­i­cal over­haul that in­cludes caps that take in­to ac­count the in­ter­est rate cy­cle or prefer­ably by scrap­ping it out­right.

But costs are not the on­ly area of IMF lend­ing that needs ur­gent re­form. Tenor mat­ters, too. Take the EFF- an in­stru­ment de­signed to ad­dress bal­ance of pay­ments im­bal­ances caused by struc­tur­al weak­ness­es in the econ­o­my. It is wide­ly ac­cept­ed that struc­tur­al re­form is a com­plex task that takes time to im­ple­ment and years to bear fruit.

Yet in the EFF we have a lend­ing in­stru­ment that dis­burs­es over on­ly three or four years and has to be re­paid in sev­en (on a weight­ed av­er­age ba­sis). A fa­cil­i­ty that is so con­strained is sim­ply not fit to sup­port struc­tur­al re­form at a time of “poly­cri­sis” and in light of the in­creas­ing­ly dev­as­tat­ing ef­fects of the cli­mate cri­sis.

Per­pet­u­al pro­grammes

It should come as no sur­prise, there­fore, that so many mid­dle-in­come coun­tries are locked in­to per­pet­u­al pro­grammes, bor­row­ing from the IMF just to re­pay the IMF. This is not good for sov­er­eign bor­row­ers, it is not good for the IMF, and it is not good for the peo­ple the IMF is meant to serve.

Forty-five years have passed since the EFF was last re­formed, in 1979. Fresh think­ing on IMF sup­port for mid­dle-in­come coun­tries, from what we know to be ded­i­cat­ed and ca­pa­ble man­age­ment and share­hold­ers, is long over­due.

It is there­fore for­tu­nate that the IMF, un­der its cur­rent lead­er­ship, has in re­cent years al­ready demon­strat­ed a ca­pac­i­ty for fresh and in­no­v­a­tive think­ing, of­ten mov­ing be­fore oth­ers. This was ev­i­dent in the quick roll­out of the RFI and the Rapid Cred­it Fa­cil­i­ty soon af­ter the pan­dem­ic broke out and the sub­se­quent al­lo­ca­tion of a record US$650 bil­lion-equiv­a­lent in SDRs.

More re­cent­ly we have seen the in­tro­duc­tion of the Re­silience and Sus­tain­abil­i­ty Fa­cil­i­ty – a fa­cil­i­ty fund­ed by rechan­nel­ing a por­tion of the new SDRs and de­signed to help fi­nance cli­mate re­silience and adap­ta­tion for coun­tries that al­ready have an IMF up­per-cred­it-tranche arrange­ment. Crit­i­cal­ly, this new fa­cil­i­ty has a fi­nal ma­tu­ri­ty of 20 years and car­ries no sur­charges.

As they con­front the mul­ti­ple crises of the ear­ly 21st cen­tu­ry, mid­dle-in­come coun­tries need lend­ing arrange­ments that are fit for pur­pose. It’s time for the IMF to switch its at­ten­tion to fun­da­men­tal re­form of its ex­ist­ing lend­ing arrange­ments for mid­dle-in­come coun­tries.

*Mia Mot­t­ley is the Prime Min­is­ter of Bar­ba­dos. Her ar­ti­cle is among those writ­ten in a spe­cial pub­li­ca­tion by world lead­ers such as Kenyan Pres­i­dent William Ru­to, Pablo Gar­cia-Sil­va, a for­mer vice-gov­er­nor of Chile’s cen­tral bank and IMF Man­ag­ing Di­rec­tor Kristali­na Georgie­va, mark­ing the 80th an­niver­sary of the IMF. (CMC)


Related articles

Sponsored

Weather

PORT OF SPAIN WEATHER

Sponsored